Skip to main content
留学咨询

辅导案例-L8S

By August 26, 2020No Comments

Pricing Better* Sourav Ray** Marketing Department, DeGroote School of Business McMaster University Hamilton ON L8S 4M4, CANADA [email protected] Li Wang CHEPA, McMaster University Hamilton ON L8S 4M4, CANADA [email protected] Daniel Levy Department of Economics, Bar-Ilan University Ramat-Gan 52900, ISRAEL, Department of Economics, Emory University Atlanta, GA 30322, USA, and Rimini Center for Economic Analysis, ITALY [email protected] Mark Bergen Department of Marketing, Carlson School of Management University of Minnesota Minneapolis, MN 55455, USA [email protected] August 16, 2019 Keywords: Retailing; Pricing; EDLP; HI-LO; Dynamic Capability; Menu Costs; Price Adjustment; Price Elasticity; Price Discovery JEL Codes: M31, E31, D22, D40, C93, L10, O33, L81 * This work has been possible thanks to grants from SSHRC Canada, Canadian Foundation for Innovation (CFI) and Ontario Research Fund – Research Infrastructure. We owe a debt of gratitude to our industry collaborators for their generous and patient help. We thank Kulothungan Jeganathan and Naeem Ahmed for excellent research assistance. We also thank numerous seminar and conference participants for their comments. We also thank Indian School of Business (ISB), Hyderabad, India, where Sourav Ray was a visiting ISB-CLMP Research Fellow in 2018 while completing a part of this research. All errors are ours. ** Corresponding author: Sourav Ray, [email protected] Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 1 Pricing Better Abstract Electronic shelf label (ESL) is an emerging price display technology around the world. While these new technologies require non-trivial investments by the retailer, they also promise significant operational efficiencies in the form of savings in material, labor and managerial costs. The presumed benefits of ESL, for example, tend to be focused around lower price adjustment costs (PAC), also known as menu costs. However, ESL not only can save PAC but may also enable the retailer to price “better,” generating greater value for the transacting parties. Thus, ESL’s strategic impact for retailers occurs between claiming these presumed efficiencies and realizing the value generating potential. Using transactions data from a longitudinal field experiment, we assess such impact of ESL by studying how it shapes retail pricing practices and outcomes. Our general finding is that ESL plays an enabling role to the retailer’s strategy – thereby enhancing the retailer’s sales and revenues. The price adjustment efficiencies of ESL allows retailers to do better waste management, price discovery, as well as leveraging value in information for consumers. However, ESL’s impact on prices is nuanced, based on the retail strategy (EDLP, HI-LO) being used. Papers quantifying emerging technologies’ impact on retail outcomes are sparse, even fewer investigating their role in pricing. To the best of our knowledge, ours is the first study to explore and quantify how ESL interacts with retail strategy to affect retail pricing practices and retail outcomes. Keywords: Retailing; Pricing; EDLP; HI-LO; Dynamic Capability; Menu Costs; Price Adjustment; Price Elasticity; Price Discovery JEL Codes: M31, E31, D22, D40, C93, L10, O33, L81 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 1 1. INTRODUCTION Electronic shelf labels (ESL) are part of an expanding array of retail technologies that include the likes of self-checkout kiosks, smart carts and a number of RFID beacon and other near field communication (NFC) applications. Despite the significant investments required, these technologies are of interest to retailers because they promise significant operational efficiencies. For example, self-checkout kiosks and smart carts save managerial time and labor costs at check out, while the several beacon and NFC applications promise savings in information gathering and communication costs by facilitating customer monitoring and customized prices and promotions. Similarly, the presumed benefits of ESL tend to focus around lower price adjustment costs (PAC). However, the impact of these new technologies may go beyond cost savings. The self-checkouts and personalized promotions may enhance customer shopping experiences, while ESL may also enable the retailer to price “better,” generating greater value for the transactions. Competitive advantage for the retailers is derived between claiming these efficiencies and realizing the value-add potential of such technologies with appropriate strategies. Unfortunately, papers quantifying emerging technologies’ impact on retail outcomes are rare, even fewer investigating their role in pricing. In particular, it is hard to find similar studies for ESL. Thus, our research questions are: How does ESL affect retail pricing and outcomes like sales volume, and revenue; and how do retailers deploy ESL to support their strategy? Note that while the basic technology has been around since the 1990s, the adoption of ESL in retail has been fragmented at best – greater popularity in Europe and Japan, and a much smaller installed base but increasing contemporary interest in China, Canada, Israel, USA etc. Recent engineering advances in the display technologies (e.g. electronic paper) have given it prominence within the expanding ecosystem of new retail technologies with falling label prices and vigorous marketing efforts driving industry adoptions. Industry research pegs potential annual growth of ESL markets to be over 15% globally, with an even higher rate of growth in the American market (Research and Markets, 2017a,b). At this rate of growth, the global installed base will almost double within the next five to six years. Surprisingly, few papers directly assess the possible impact of ESL on retail pricing and outcomes. For example, several papers allude to the potential of ESL to impact retail prices and pricing practices, either directly or by enabling strategic capabilities of the retailer (cf. Levy et al. 1997; Dutta et al. 2003; Zbaracki et al. 2004; Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 2 Ray et al. 2006; Bergen, et al. 2008; Gedenk et al. 2010; Grewal et al. 2011; Bolton and Shankar 2018). Yet, none directly estimate such impacts. To the best of our knowledge, Garaus et al. (2016) is the only published paper that assess the direct impact of ESL. However, their focus is on consumer perceptions of ESL, not ESL’s impact on retail pricing and outcomes. This lack of attention is quite surprising as it creates a serious gap in our understanding of pricing technologies. Not only are ESL systems large strategic investments by the retailers, the retail deployment of ESL with its lower price adjustment costs is presumed to have a direct impact on the extent of price rigidity and flexibility, which play a central role in modern macro and monetary economics literature. For example, the modern New Keynesian Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (New Keynesian DSGE) model, the workhorse model used for monetary policy analysis, critically depends on the response of prices to monetary policy shocks, which in turn, depends on the extent of price rigidity. Many monetary economy models need a high degree of price rigidity to match aggregate data patterns. Among the existing theories of price rigidity, perhaps the best known and the most popular is the price adjustment cost (PAC), also called the “menu cost” theory (Barro 1972, Sheshinski and Weiss 1977, Mankiw 1985, Ball and Mankiw 1994). According to this theory, prices are rigid and thus adjust sluggishly because it is costly to change them. The natural conclusion is prices will be less rigid with ESL. Yet, there is limited evidence supporting this outcome. In recent years, an emerging literature in marketing has explored how the extent of variation in micro-level price rigidity is an outcome of strateg
ic decisions (Ray et al. 2006; 2012). These suggest, the deployment of ESL may be only partially predictive of the extent to which prices are rigid. Moreover, the menu cost models assume that the PACs are exogenously generated—either fixed and independent of the size of price change (Mankiw 1985), or convex, where cost increases with the size of price change (Rotemberg, 1982, 1987). In contrast, another developing literature in business and economics, explicitly consider PACs as endogenous to organizational factors such as strategic capabilities (Zbaracki et al. 2004; Hallberg 2017). To this end, ESL technology, which require large expenses and significant organizational changes to realize its benefits, can be seen as resources that build strategic capabilities, whose return on investments would depend on its effectiveness in supporting a given retail strategy. Thus the same technology may support very different retail pricing strategies associated with very different realized price adjustment costs. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 3 In this paper, we contend that technologies like ESLs are strategic investments that enhance the retailer’s strategic capabilities. These capabilities enable retailers to create and claim value by effective deployment of their strategy and more effective prices. To understand the mechanism of its impact, we investigate how ESL affects price sensitivity, price adjustments and price discovery efforts of the retailer. Our empirical design is a pseudo field experiment comprising transactions data from two supermarkets that implemented ESL. Our analyses use standard econometric models including Differences-in-Difference (DID), etc. Our general finding is that ESL plays an enabling role to the retailer’s strategy, offering significant value-oriented benefits beyond cost efficiency. We find the impact on price sensitivity, price adjustment patterns, and price discovery modes of the retailers are consistent with these different roles of ESL. We also find that the nature and scale of ESL’s impact on retail prices is contextual with greater price rigidity observed in some situations. These indicate that the impact of ESL is highly nuanced. To the best of our knowledge, we are the first to explore and quantify how a price display technology like ESL interacts with retail strategy to affect retail pricing and its outcomes. In the rest of the paper, we first discuss the ESL technology and the related literature in section 2. We describe our data in section 3, in particular – the supermarket stores from which we get our data, their respective positioning strategies and specific use cases for the ESL implementation. In section 4, we describe the experimental set up identifying the treatment and control groups. In section 5, we specify the empirical models estimating the impact of ESL on retail outcomes, price sensitivity, price adjustment patterns and price discovery, and present the results. A discussion of the results and their implications for research and practice is in section 6. Section 7 concludes by pointing out some limitations and future areas of study. 2. ELECTRONIC SHELF LABELS AND RELATED LITERATURE Electronic Shelf Labels (ESL) are electronic label displays that, for the most part, replace paper tags. Sometimes, also referred to as electronic price tags or as electronic point of purchase (EPOP) displays, these labels are typically based on LCD or electronic paper (e-paper) technologies. The labels are wirelessly connected to a central computer, typically in the back office of the retailer. This allows the retailer to change the information displayed on the labels throughout the stores (typically prices) practically with a single keystroke. The database for the Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 4 displays are integrated with the point of sale (POS) systems used at store checkout. Economies of Scale in Physical Price Adjustment Costs (Menu Costs) One immediate and obvious benefit of ESL systems in a multi-product setting is their ability to cut dramatically the physical price adjustment costs (menu costs) of the traditional paper-tag based price system, to the point where the menu cost of adjusting one additional price is close to zero, or perhaps even zero. Thus, ESL systems introduce economies of scale in price adjustment technology, letting the retailer adjust the price of a given good more frequently while incurring a fraction of the cost. These savings can be substantial in light of the existing empirical evidence. For example, Levy et al (1997, 1998) and Dutta et al (1999) use time and motion measurements data on paper-price tag based price adjustment processes, which were collected by an ESL system manufacturer. The company collected these data in order to measure and validate the cost savings that their system could generate. Using these data, Levy et al (1997, 1998) report that the annual menu costs at large US supermarket chains average about $105,887 per store (in 1991–1992 prices).1 In relative terms, the total estimated menu costs, which equal $0.52 per price change on average, comprise 0.70 percent of revenues and 35.2 percent of net margins, suggesting that the magnitude of the menu cost is substantial. Dutta et al (1999) report comparable menu cost estimates for a large US drugstore chain. There are no comparable cost estimates with ESL. However, it is safe to conclude conservatively, ESLs would save the bulk of these physical price adjustment costs. Managerial Price Adjustment Costs Going beyond the physical menu costs, there is an emerging literature that calibrates the managerial and customer costs of price adjustments. The ESL’s role in these other components of the PACs is unclear. Zbaracki et al (2004) try to shed light on the magnitude of the managerial cost of price adjustment. They conduct time and motion measurements of price adjustment processes at a one-billion-dollar US industrial manufacturing company and its customers. They find that the managerial costs of price adjustment are more than 6 times, and the customer costs of price adjustment are more than 20 times the menu cost. In dollar terms, 1 In 2019 prices, this would be equivalent to $199,131. For large chains, these figures amount to significant sums of money. For example, one of the supermarket chains included in the data that Levy et al (1997) study, was operating about 500 stores in that period. For this particular supermarket chain, the annual chain-wide menu cost comes to about $100 million, a non-negligible figure. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 5 they find the total annual cost of price adjustment in 1997 is $1,216,445.2 Of this amount, 3.57% is the menu cost, 23.03% is the managerial cost which includes the cost of information gathering and analysis, systems cost, and the cost of the managerial time spent on the evaluation and decision of price changes, and 73.40% is the customer cost of price adjustment. So, conservatively, even if the managerial and customer costs of ESL are similar to that of paper labels, the potential for saving the physical menu costs are still significant. However, there is reason to believe, ESLs introduce significant economies even in the managerial costs of price adjustments. Much of these managerial costs derive from the time and effort required by managers to decide on what prices to implement. Large price changes can be especially onerous. ESL systems make small price changes profitable. For example, under the existing manual, posted paper price tag based system, small price changes might not be worthwhile because their fixed cost may exceed the benefits. The ESL systems, by reducing the menu costs to zero (or close to zero), make such small price changes profitable. For example, Levy et al. (1997) report that the supermarket chains in their sample, in an aver
age week experience cost increases on about 800–1,000 products they sell. However, the supermarkets adjust prices of only about 70–80 percent of these products. The remaining 20–30 percent of the prices are not adjusted immediately because the existing menu costs make the necessary price adjustments unprofitable. ESL systems would make these smaller price changes profitable, and thus the chain would leave less money on the table.3 Economies of Scope ESL systems also have the ability to adjust many prices with a click of a button, suggesting that these systems introduce economies of scope as well in the price adjustment technology, an idea that was suggested by Lach and Tsiddon (1996, 2007), to explain the within-store synchronization and cross-store staggering of price changes that they found in their data.4 Newer versions of the ESL technology come with enhanced graphics and display options that allow the retailer to provide myriad information, including, but not limited to branding, 2 In 2019 prices, this is equivalent to $2,287,646. 3 Consistent with these empirical observations, in standard theoretical menu cost models that economists frequently use, prices do not adjust to small shocks. In some models, the shocks need to be exceptionally large for prices to start adjusting. See, for example, Karadi and Reiff (2012). 4 Alvarez and Lippi (2014), Baudry et al (2007), Dhyne and Konieczny (2007), Levy et al (1997), Midrigan (2011), Cavallo (2018), and Dutta, et al (1999) offer a model and/or evidence that is consistent with this characterization of price change processes. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 6 competitor information, vendor promotions, quality and product attributes, price discount ending date, etc. So, ESL systems enable the company managers to monitor and adjust not only the prices, but also the quantities, the inventories, promotional information, competitive information, vendor management, nutritional value information, etc. In other words, the economies of scope that comes with ESL systems, covers wider range of business activities and resource use. Price Discovery An important advantage of an ESL system over the existing paper price tag based system that is related to these managerial costs, is its ability to allow price experimentation. Price experimentation and price discovery practices seem to be far more common than the literature recognizes. There is evidence that the type of price adjustment practices sometimes retailers are engaged in, can be best explained by a model in which there is an uncertainty about the demand elasticity and/or about competitive factors. Under these circumstances, the firms are unable to price optimally. To overcome these difficulties, it might be optimal for the firms to engage in price experimentation, in order to discover the right price, by trial and error. Theoretically, the optimality of these types of activities that involve price learning and discovery, has been demonstrated by Rustichini and Wolinsky (1995), Balvers and Cosimano (1993), and Aghion et al. (1991), among others. On the empirical front, Argente and Yeh (2016) find that the prices of new products change twice as often as the prices of the average product. In addition, they find that the average size of these adjustments is at least 50 percent larger than the average price change. They show that a menu cost model with price experimentation can rationalize these findings. Bachmann and Moscarini (2011) present evidence that is consistent with a model of monopolistic competition in which there is imperfect information about the demand, but the firm gradually learns and discovers its price elasticity from the sales volume. Keil et al (2001) report that managers that were assigned long-term goals were engaged in more price experimentation, in comparison to the managers that were assigned short-term goals. Campbell and Eden (2014) also document micro- level price behavior, which is consistent with a model that incorporates experimentation. ESL makes it feasible to review and consider price adjustments of varying frequency as well as of varying sizes by conducting small scale, within-store, pricing and price adjustment experiments, almost at any level, at the shelf-level, at the product level, at the category level, at Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 7 the zone level, etc., at low cost. ESL systems can be linked to the companies’ inventory and financial management software, and therefore learning, analyzing, and discovering the bottom- line profitability scenarios and outcomes of such pricing experiments can be accomplished quickly and efficiently, at relatively low cost. This capability of the ESL systems is particularly beneficial because in the absence of experimentation, a full optimization requires a complete knowledge of all the relevant information, which would be prohibitively costly to gather and process. Experimentation of the type we are discussing here is perhaps not the first best, but given its feasibility and its low cost, it can be a very cost-effective in terms of the learning speed as well as effectiveness. Price Coordination across Markets/Regions Adams and Williams (2019) note that many large multi-store retailers do not always price on a store-by-store or even on a market-by-market basis. Instead, they observe, prices are set on a zone-by-zone basis, where each zone spans several markets that form a heterogeneous group. DellaVigna and Gentzkow (2019) find that most US food, drugstore and mass merchandise chains charge nearly uniform prices across stores despite wide variation in consumer demographics and the level of competition. Based on price elasticity estimates, they conclude that the average chain sacrifices 7 percent of profits relative to a benchmark of flexible prices. This pricing practice may be due the chains’ to inability to efficiently manage heterogeneous pricing profiles across large number of stores and/or markets. The ESL technology has the potential to make geographically segmented pricing and price adjustment processes practically and logistically more feasible as well as more cost efficient. The ability of the ESL to permit small-sample experiments and price discovery exercises at low cost, will permit more optimal pricing adapted to local settings. Strategic Benefits and Consumer Value There are other, less obvious advantages of ESL systems. The economies of scale in changing prices can allow retailers manage waste more effectively, especially for perishable products. They can change prices more frequently (e.g. several times a day or even by the hour, instead of once a day or week), and can time and grade them to achieve higher sales yields and lesser excess inventory at the end of the selling cycle. The ability to make small price changes discussed earlier, have important strategic Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 8 implications. Ray et al. (2006) study a theoretical model, where a strategically minded wholesaler with low enough menu costs, takes advantage of the menu cost that the retailer faces to make frequent “small” price increases. The retailer is unable to pass-through these because of the menu cost s/he faces. Such small price changes can also be key strategic imperatives for retailers in consumer electronic markets as shown in Ray et al. (2012). Chen et al (2008) show that frequent small price changes exist at the retail food markets as well. The integration of the ESL systems with the same POS database that is connected to the checkout counters minimizes chances of a mismatch between the shelf price and the checkout price (over or under ring), leading to greater consumer confidence in prices. Bergen et al. (2008) discuss the potential significance of such confidence for both retailers and policy making. The savings in time and efforts of the in-store execution
and management staff can be channeled into providing more streamlined and effective service to improve customer experience. These complement the sleek designs of ESL, which can improve the look and feel of a store, creating a more positive image compared to stores with older technology (Garaus et al. 2016). Some argue that the standardized design of price displays may even mute the salience of prices and enhance the utility of other non-price related attributes of the retailer (Soutjis, et al. 2017), thereby reducing the consumer’s price sensitivity. ESL and Retail Strategic Positioning Overall, the potential impacts of ESLs appear to come in essentially two different forms. The first is efficiency in terms of cost savings – both physical menu costs as well as managerial price adjustment costs. The second is the added value ESL creates for retailers and consumers. It enables retailers to manage its price adjustments strategically, find better prices and in turn, being able to offer greater value to its customers. Between realizing these efficiencies and claiming the added value, retailers can generate better gross margins for themselves. Nevertheless, the process by which these higher margins are to be generated completely depends on the strategic focus of the retailer. For some retailers, frequent price changes are a core part of their strategic positioning. Certainly, ESL would potentially result in cost savings for such retailers. However, the potential for ESLs to support even greater flexibility in prices may be less compelling for these retailers than supporting higher margins due to added value and reduced salience of prices. For other retailers, price consistency may be the core of their Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 9 strategic positioning. Thus, both cost savings from frequent price changes as well as the potential of ESLs to support flexible prices may be moot for such retailers. Yet, ESL systems may enhance these retailers’ ability to find the right prices to support such consistency. A key upshot of this line of thinking is to suggest that while ESL may reduce PAC, it may not necessarily lead to less rigid prices, which would depend on retail strategy. 3. DATA The data for our study comes from two different supermarket stores in the North-West Milan region of Italy. We will call them stores S and M. Both belong to one of the largest grocery store operators in the country, which has over 1,000 stores. Both stores are owned and operated by individual store management. The parent company had worked collaboratively with a consulting company specializing in POS technology, to install ESL in limited scale in the two stores. ESL was installed in the Fresh Fruits and Vegetables departments of both stores as well as in the Delicatessen department of store M. One of the objectives of the installation was to assess the potential return on such investments, over an extended period of deployment. Our data comprises of two types. First, we have records of sales-receipts generated at the POS over a two-year period, spanning the date when ESL was installed. In particular, for store S, we have 445,252 receipts for 105 weeks (July 16, 2007–July 16, 2009); with ESL installed in the 60th week (September 16, 2008). For store M, we have 384,475 receipts for 106 weeks (July 3, 2007–July 23, 2009); with ESL installed in the 70th week (November 18, 2009). Second, we received privileged access to some confidential internal reports and white papers of the company. Our descriptive details are drawn from the information in the written reports, while the statistical analyses are based on the POS sales records. Store Size and Operations The stores are largely similar to each other in many respects including size, gross profit percentages and growth. Based on the sales data of 6 months before the ESL installation in 2008, we estimate the annual sales revenue of store S to be in the range of 2.5 million Euros, and that of store M to be about 2.6 million Euros. The average purchase per receipt is higher for store S at €24.75 than for store M at €15.58. However, store S has an average of about 1,900 consumer transactions per week, compared to about 3,200 for store M. Based on internal documents from 2009, both have similar gross profit percentages at 35% and 37.5%, Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 10 respectively, and similar sales growth trajectories for comparable categories (3%). However, we find that there are differences in expenses as a percentage of sales, 23.8% at store S vs. 4.2% at store M. The staff at store S is mostly comprised of temporary and inexperienced workers, while that of store M is comprised of more skilled, department managers. This reflects in the average wage rate for store S (at £9/hr) being significantly less than that of store M (£12/hr). That said, there are important distinctions between the stores when it comes to their strategic retail positioning and their purported use of the ESL technology. ESL for Store Pricing Practices – EDLP and HI-LO Positioning From a description of their pricing processes, we know that store S prices are based on warehouse price margins. Yet, pricing consistency is deemed very important and changes in cost are not immediately reflected in prices, and there are only few promotions. This type of pricing is generally associated with Every Day Low Price (EDLP) positioning. EDLP retailers aim to provide value to consumers by maintaining a high level of price consistency and reducing instances and salience of periodic price promotions. In contrast, in store M, maintaining price consistency is less important with around 50% of prices changing daily, only some of which may be due to cost changes. In fact, the store manager can set its own selling price, and not necessarily as a margin on warehouse price. This type of pricing is consistent with HI-LO positioning. HI-LO retailers aim to provide value to consumers and draw traffic to the store by frequent price promotions over its product lines. As a pricing technology that purports to give enhanced ability to the retailer at managing price changes, ESL appears to have a direct role to play in implementing these retail strategies – greater price consistency in EDLP and more effective price changes in HI-LO. A key focus in the assessment of return on investment (ROI) was the ESL’s role in better implementation of the retail strategies. Figure 1 plots the average weekly prices for two random treatment group product for the two stores. Note here store S has fewer price changes than store M in a similar time period – as would be expected from the description above. Visually it is difficult to discern any specific change in pattern between pre- and post-ESL installation weeks. ESL for Waste Management Waste management was another key focus of the ROI analyses. However, the stores differed Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 11 significantly. Acting proactively to clear unsold inventory of perishables was a major concern for store S. Typically, the department manager would reduce prices at the end of the day to sell off unsold produce. This came with several challenges. First, the manual task of managing price reductions across a number of products is non-trivial. Second, discounts could be too deep, leaving money on the table, or too shallow, resulting in unsold produce. ESL could enable the managers to run more efficient “on special” promotions as opposed to engaging in a fire sale of unsold inventory. ESL could also help price better, resulting in less “extra” inventory towards the end of the day, as well as discounting just enough, and no more, to get the desired sales lift. In contrast, waste management was not a big managerial concern for store M. In the perishable Fruits and Vegetables department a waste of 5%–7% was considered acceptable. In th
e Delicatessen department where products are normally cut to order, wastage was negligible. ESL for Consumer Information Consumer information was also a focus of the ROI from ESL. Strict Italian fresh food labeling laws require detailed and accurate provenance information be displayed at point of purchase, with heavy fines imposed on retailers for noncompliance. So both stores were keen to avoid such fines. ESL could reduce the costs of compliance by making the process of providing such information more efficient when products were repriced, re-shelved, and during inventory changeovers. However, ESL would allow the stores to easily provide additional information not mandated by law, such as competitor pricing information or additional non-price attributes. This is where the stores differed. While store S focused on compliance, store M aimed at going beyond and provide additional information such as region of origin, flavor, etc. across its product lines. This would presumably give greater value to its customers, resulting in a sales lift and contributing further to the ROI. ESL and Managerial Supervision Last but not the least, was the concern with managerial time-savings. Recent legal changes in Italy required stores to provide additional data for livestock such as where the animal was raised, where slaughtered and where butchered, along with license numbers for the slaughterer and butcher. The item purchased must contain this data for full traceability. The volume and variability of the information made this a non-trivial task. While at the time this law only Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 12 applied to beef, the externalities of such regulatory attention meant there was a heightened sensitivity for managerial supervision and monitoring of staff compliance across the store. ESL was expected to introduce more economies of scale for both stores by centralizing such efforts. In summary, the key differences in the use of ESL across the stores were in the implementation of strategic price positioning – EDLP for store S, HI-LO for store M; greater emphasis on efficient waste management for store S; and greater emphases on value through consumer information for store M. 4. EXPERIMENTAL DESIGN AND MEASUREMENT ISSUES Recall that ESL was installed in the fresh fruits and vegetables (F&V) department in store S and in both F&V and Delicatessen departments in store M. Given the before-the ESL- installation and after-the-ESL-installation data, we have a pseudo experimental setup to study the impact of ESL on retail outcomes (price, sales volume and revenue) in these departments. For purposes of comparability, we only analyse the F&V department. In experimental design terms, this would be considered the treatment group. However, a simple before- and after-comparison would not be able to isolate the impact of ESL since several unobserved variables that vary over time might confound the results. Therefore, for identification purposes, i.e. to isolate the effect of ESL, we need to choose an appropriate department as a control group. Choice of Control Group Ideally, this control department would be similar to the treatment department such that it would be affected by all the potential unobserved variables, except that it will not be affected by ESL. Since there are several departments other than F&V in the stores, where ESL was not installed, all of them are potential candidates as control departments. We select a specific control in the following three steps: (1) Select candidate daily purchase categories, preferably food related. At this stage, we selected the following five departments: Fresh Meat, Dairy Products, Bread, Deep-Frozen Food, General Store. (2) From the above we then select a subset with similar average price, volume and revenue changes over time. This resulted in the following three departments: Fresh Meat, Bread, General Store. We then dropped General Store and Bread, for we did not have enough observations in both stores. This left Fresh Meat as the candidate control department. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 13 (3) Lastly, we checked if Fresh Meat exhibits similar time trends before and after ESL. A similar trend offers additional assurance that Fresh Meat is independent of ESL and thus a good control. For this we ran the following regression: ( ) ( )2 21 2 3 4 5 t t t ty t t ESL t ESL t ESLα β β β β β ε= + + + × + × + + (1) where ty is the dependent variable (price, sales volume, or revenue of Fresh Meat) in week t, tESL is a binary variable which equals 1 if t is after implementation of the ESL and 0, if before, and tε is the error term. A significant 3β or 4β coefficient would suggest that the trend differs between before and after ESL. We run this analyses for both stores and find strong evidence that there is no such ESL dependency – five out of the six regressions return insignificant coefficients. Thus we conclude that Fresh Meat is an appropriate control department for our identification purposes.5 Data Aggregation and Descriptive Statistics Recall that our data is at a highly disaggregate, individual purchase incident level. This allows us to track individual products over time. To ensure relative balance we use 53 weeks’ data before ESL installation, for both stores. We then use most of the available weeks in the post installation period – 42 weeks for store S (EDLP) and 33 weeks for store M (HI-LO). We drop four weeks (2 weeks before and 2 weeks after) around the installation date to filter out any disruption due to installation. Each product in our data is identified by a 13 digit EAN (European Article Number) code and is classified as belonging to one of 25 “departments” which are the broad store categories like F&V (our treatment category), Fresh Meat (our control category), etc. For store S (EDLP), the before-ESL and after-ESL number of products in the sample were (26, 26) for the treatment group and (17, 11) for the control group. Correspondingly, for store M (HI-LO) the before-ESL and after-ESL number of products in the sample were (335, 273) for the treatment group and (61, 87) for the control group. To adjust for the unbalanced nature of the sample between the treatment and the control groups, we use robust estimates in our analyses. We aggregate the data for each EAN code in the two departments at a weekly level. 5 The results of the analyses for control group selection are presented in the Appendix, in Tables A2 and A3. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 14 Computing the average weekly unit price is not straightforward. We first calculate the unit prices for each receipt in a given day from the recorded gross price divided by the units. We then compute the median of such unit prices as our daily central tendency measure. For the weekly unit price, we take the average of the daily medians. We impute missing unit prices with previous period price only if the number of continuous missing weeks is less than or equal to 2. We had to exclude approximately 36% of the original data – mostly products sold by weight, for which we did not have enough information to calculate the unit price. After accounting for missing data (e.g., not all products are purchased every week) and the aggregations, the total number of observations we have for store S (EDLP) are 422 before-ESL, and 302 after-ESL, for the treatment (F&V) category. The corresponding numbers are 422 and 389 for the control (Fresh Meat) category. For store M, the number of observations are 9,097 and 4,543 for the treatment category, and 1,636 and 1,402 for the control category, respectively. See Table 1. In Table 2, we report some descriptive statistics pertaining to price, volume sales and revenue in our sample. The average prices in store S increase (e.g. from
1.59 to 2.58 for treatment group), while that of store M remain similar (e.g. 1.73 to 1.69). The average sales volume for store S decreases (12.88 to 9.36) while that of store M remains similar (22.96 vs. 23.13). Revenue in both cases remain similar (19.61 vs. 18.83, and 36.90 vs. 35.30 – in ×100 Euros – for store S and store M, respectively). While we restrict our analyses to F&V and Fresh Meat departments, we also looked at the store-wide sales figures by comparing the number of transactions and average value of the receipt level transactions six months before and after the ESL installation. The average transactions of the store are marginally better in the post-ESL period (25.79 vs. 24.75, and 16.83 vs. 15.58, for store S and store M respectively). However, there is some drop in the average number of transactions per week for store S (1,925 to 1,880), and a small increase for store M (3,255 to 3,304). See Table 3. However, not much can be inferred from these descriptive numbers in terms of the impact of ESL on the retail outcomes. For that we now turn to the econometric analyses. 5. EMPIRICAL MODEL ESTIMATIONS AND RESULTS Our primary empirical objective is to investigate how the ESL technology can enable and Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 15 complement different retail strategies. In the process we study both, the impact of ESL on retail outcomes, viz. prices, volume and revenue, as well as the process by which such an impact operates. We start by assessing the impact of ESL on price, volume and revenue and how these differ for the different stores, and discuss the robustness checks we conduct. Then, to get insights into the processes that operate for different retail strategies, we estimate ESL’s impact on price sensitivity for the different stores, along with several robustness checks of our results. The next analysis investigates ESL’s impact on price adjustment patterns of the different stores as further investigation into the determining processes. The last analysis explores whether ESL impacts the price discovery efforts of a retailer. Impact of ESL on Price, Sales Volume and Gross Revenue – Difference-in-Difference To estimate the impact of ESL we use the Difference-in-Difference (DID) model. DID is a quasi-experimental method used to measure the effect of a treatment or intervention over time. It allows for comparisons over time for a non-random sample by comparing the treatment group before and after an intervention, with a suitably matched control group that does not receive the intervention. DID with Pooled Data We first pool the data from both stores to run the following basic model: ln () = + () + () + ( × ) + + + + (2) where, jity refers to the dependent variable of interest (price, sales volume, revenue) – for store j, product (SKU/EAN) i, and week t. TD is a dummy variable, which equals 1 if product i belongs to the treatment department, and 0 otherwise; ESL is a dummy variable, which equals 1 if week t is after the ESL intervention, and 0 otherwise; jµ is a fixed effect for store, iϑ is a fixed effect for products, and tτ is a fixed effect for week. jitε is the error term. We use robust standard error estimates to deal with potential heteroscedasticity of the error terms. There are two reasons why we use the natural log transformation. First, our data is highly skewed with large variance. Using the natural log transformation flattens the spread and reduces Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 16 the impact of the outliers.6 Second, using ln( )jity makes the interpretation of the coefficient δ particularly convenient; it is the post-ESL change of the treatment group response as a percentage of the control group. The results of the pooled DID is reported in Table 4(a). We find that following ESL installation, there is a marginally significant decrease in unit price of the treatment group relative to the control group (δ = –0.021; p = 0.056). On the other hand, sales volume and gross revenue shows a significant increase by 9.8% (δ = 0.098; p = 0.002) and 7.3% (δ = 0.073; p = 0.023), respectively. DID by Store We next run the same DID analyses separately for the two stores to check if ESL has different impact on the two stores. For this we run the following model, separately for each store: ln () = + () + () + ( × ) + + + (3) Since we run the analyses separately for each store, this model is identical with the earlier model except that we do not have the subscript j and the store fixed effect jµ . Table 4, panels (b) and (c) report the estimation results. The results show that for store S (EDLP), post-ESL treatment group responses are significantly higher than pre-ESL levels: unit price is higher by 13% (δ = 0.131; p = 0.001), sales volume is higher by 17% (δ = 0.174; p = 0.003), and gross revenue is higher by 31% (δ = 0.308; p = 0.000), compared to the control group. These numbers are substantial and are all statistically significant at the 1% level. For store M (HI-LO), the results are more of a mixed bag. While there is no statistically significant change in unit price levels (δ = –0.018, p = 0.132), sales volume exhibits an increase of 8% (δ = 0.082, p = 0.017) relative to the control group. Gross revenue also exhibits an increase of about 6% (δ = 0.058; p = 0.091), though only significant at the 10% level.7 Robustness Check – Placebo Interventions To rule out the possibility that the estimation results are an artifact of the DID method, we conducted the placebo test. For this we separated the pre-ESL and post-ESL data and introduced 6 In the Appendix, in Figure A1, we assess the impact of natural log transformation on our data. 7 We present the summary results in the Appendix, in Figure A2. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 17 arbitrary intervention points in each. We then proceeded to conduct the DID estimation for each of these arbitrary specifications. A significant δ coefficient will reject the null hypothesis that there is no placebo effect. Recall that for store S, the actual ESL installation was on the 63rd week. For the placebo test in the pre-ESL sample, we introduced weeks 23, 33 and 43 as intervention points. Similarly, for the post-ESL sample, we specified weeks 73 and 83. For store M, where the original ESL installation was done on week 70, we specified weeks 30, 40 and 50 for the pre-ESL sample; and weeks 80 and 90 for the post-ESL sample. So, we are able to do 2 (store) × 3 (response variables) × 5 (intervention points), i.e. 30 comparisons. A large majority (26 out of 30) of the coefficients are not significant statistically, suggesting that our estimation results are not an artifact of the DID specification.8 Impact of ESL on Price Sensitivity We next focus on assessing how ESL affects price sensitivity of the treatment group. There are several reasons to believe ESL will have an effect on consumers’ response to retail prices. In principle, to the extent retailers are able to discover “better” prices, they are able to generate greater response from the consumer. Smaller price reductions, for example, might result in the same demand lift as higher reductions were getting earlier. This will reflect in the data as higher price sensitivity. On the other hand, to the extent retailers are able to offer diagnostic information that is valuable to the consumer, through the use of ESL, they may succeed in moving the consumer focus away from a price-centric purchase decision to a more value-centric one. This could reflect in the data as lesser price sensitivity. In addition, ESLs could also free up staff time from managing and supervising pricing processes to customer service, further contributing to perceptions of value (Levy et al 2010). As well, ESLs migh
t also contribute to a cleaner and more sophisticated look and feel of the store, enhancing the shopping experience and also contributing to the perceptions of value. To estimate price sensitivity, we use the standard Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ADL) models. Our basic specification is an ADL(1,1) model, as follows: () = α + 1 �,−1� + β2 () + β3 �,−1� + 1 () ∗ +2 �,−1� ∗ + 3 + + (4) 8 A summary of the results are in the Appendix, in Table A4. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 18 where, itq and itp are respectively, the quantity sold and unit price of product i in week t; ESL is a dummy variable which equals 1 if t is after ESL installation, and 0 if before; iϑ is product fixed effect and itε is the error term. Using the natural log-log specifications have the twin advantage of muting the impact of outliers as well as offering a convenient interpretation of the regression parameters. In particular, price elasticity can be calculated from the estimated coefficients, as: Price Elasticity 2 1 ESLβ γ= + × (5) Endogeneity and Instrumental Variables One of the challenges of the earlier specification is the potential endogeneity between itp and itq . Not only does price affect the quantity demanded but quantity might also affect the prices set by the retailer, making price potentially correlated with the error term. It might be worthwhile to mention here that since our data comes from a single retailer who has price setting power, the endogeneity problem might not be as severe as in more aggregate data sets with multiple, possibly multi-store retailers, who set prices for multiple stores and multiple products. In our case, it is more likely that the retailer only has control over prices that he uses to get a response in terms of quantity demanded. Nevertheless, we address the potential endogeneity with a standard two-stage-least-squares approach using instrumental variables. The desired characteristic of good instruments is that they will be correlated with the endogenous variable, in our case itp , but uncorrelated with the dependent variable, in our case itq . We consider two broad types of instruments. First, we take the average prices of available “other” categories as instruments. Specifically, we consider the average prices of the following categories: Canned food, Canned non-food (only for Store S), Delicatessen, and Dairy and Bread (only for Store M). The average retail prices are a big part of a retailer’s price positioning; for example, they distinguish between high-price versus low-price retailers. Therefore, these “other” category prices are expected to be correlated with price levels of the treatment group; but are otherwise not expected to be correlated with the treatment group quantity sold. Second, we take advantage of the data on the store’s loyalty program, to construct the following instrument: = ∑ ∈() (6) Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 19 where ( )r r t∈ are all receipts in week t. Here jirLoyal are the loyalty points earned in store j, in a particular receipt r that included purchase of product i. Pointsjit is the sum of all loyalty points in receipts including the purchase of product i in a particular week t. jitPoints is constructed such that it satisfies two key characteristics. First, more frequently purchased products get assigned more jitPoints compared to those that are not. This is by construction. Since more frequently purchased products are likely to be priced differently than products not purchased as frequently, jitPoints would be correlated with jitp . Second, jitPoints is related to the total monetary value of the purchase and not the quantity of individual product purchases. Hence, purchase quantity of the product jitq , is uncorrelated with jitPoints . Thus, jitPoints appears to be a good instrument for jitp . We run the analyses separately for the two stores. The estimation results are reported in Table 5. Note the distinct nature of the coefficients. 2β is not significant for store S (EDLP) whereas it is for store M (HI-LO) ( 2β = –9.752). This is consistent with the different strategic positioning of the stores since the EDLP stores do not change much prices, while the HI-LO stores depend on periodic promotions to draw traffic. The coefficient 1γ is statistically significant and negative for store S (–6.896) suggesting that the demand is more price sensitive post-ESL. On the other hand, 1γ is statistically significant and positive for store M (1.512) suggesting demand is less price sensitive post-ESL. Calculating the pre-ESL and post-ESL price elasticity for the two stores, we get the price elasticity (in absolute value) of store S (EDLP) increases from – 0.402 (not statistically significant) to –7.297 (statistically significant); while that of store M (HI- LO) decreases from –9.752 to –8.240 (statistically significant). Robustness Checks for Price Sensitivity Patterns – Alternate First Difference Specifications To check that the price sensitivity patterns evident in the estimated elasticities above are robust, we ran the following alternate first difference specification. ( ) ( ) ( )1 2 1ln ln lnit it it i itq p ESL p ESLα β β γ ϑ ε∆ = + ∆ + + ∆ × + + (7) We use the first differenced values of the same variables used earlier, as instruments for ( )ln itp∆ . The results are reported in Table 6. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 20 The price sensitivity parameter is 1 1 ESLβ γ+ × with 1γ capturing the change in price sensitivity post-ESL. For store S (EDLP), 1γ is –2.061 (p < 0.01) suggesting price sensitivity increases in the post-ESL period. On the other hand, for store M (HI-LO), 1γ is 1.830 (p < 0.01) suggesting price sensitivity decreases in the post-ESL period. Note that this pattern is exactly the same as in the ADL(1,1) specification. Impact of ESL on Price Adjustments We turn our focus next on investigating the price adjustment patterns of the stores in the pre- and post-ESL periods. Specifically, we estimate the average percentage price changes, separately for price increases and decreases, as follows: ( ), 1 , 1% / % % 0 % % 0 it it i t i t it it it it it it p p p p p p if p p p if p − − + − ∆ = − ∆ = ∆ ∆ > ∆ =   ∆ <  ∆    (8) The estimation results are given in Table 7. For store S (EDLP), the average price reductions decrease from 47.2% before ESL to 28.3% after ESL. At the same time, the average price increases also decrease from 45.1% before ESL to 11.2% after ESL. So, there seems to be overall, lesser magnitude of price changes after ESL. Indeed the average magnitude of price changes decrease from 45.3% before ESL to 11.7% after ESL. In contrast, for store M (HI-LO), the average price reductions are almost unchanged between 19.9% before ESL to 19.3% after ESL. However, average price increases marginally increase from 13.1% to 15.2%. Overall, the magnitude of average price changes go up from 14.9% to 16.3%, a modest increase. We summarize the price changes in Figure 2. Impact of ESL on Price Discovery One of the key presumed advantages of ESL is that it gives the retailer the ability to change prices more readily than it can with paper labels. A corollary of this is that retailer may be better positioned to set prices based on more current information. As the business environment changes, the retailer faces the challenge of not only interpreting and analyzing such changes to decide whether and how those should impact its prices, but also implement changes should that be needed. The retailer’s analyses of current information can happen in multiple ways. While it Electronic copy available at: h ttps://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 21 can use existing models, routines and heuristics to map the information to its pricing choices, it could also run small in-store control experiments to learn how different prices, information or product mix combine in a given situation to affect its revenue outcomes. The combination of these efforts and a consideration of any of several possible objectives such as maximizing revenue, traffic, market shares, gross margins etc., inform the retailer’s decisions on what prices to choose. We call this exercise “price discovery” by the retailer. In the absence of direct observation and access to retail decision makers, it is difficult to impute these activities from POS data. However, one of the implications of ESL is that, not only can the retailer implement price changes easily, but knowing that, the retailer is also more likely to engage in more frequent and current price discovery. This would then reflect in the post-ESL prices incorporating more contemporaneous information than the pre-ESL prices. To explore this possibility, we use a general autoregressive model specification on unit prices and estimate the maximum duration of lagged impact for model fit. ESL driven price discovery would suggest that the duration of such lagged impact would be shorter in the post ESL sample since it would have used more current information. ( ) ( ), , , , 1 ln ln r i t i k i t k i t k p pα β ε− = = + +∑ (9) For each product, we estimate the maximum lag r as being the higher of the two criteria: AIC (Akaike’s Information Criterion) and SBIC (Schwarz‘s Bayesian Information Criterion). We are able to do this analysis only for store M (HI-LO) since store S (EDLP) did not have sufficient price changes to estimate the parameters. We find that the average lag after ESL (2.13 weeks) is significantly smaller than the average lag before ESL (3.21). This is consistent with more efficient price discovery discussed here.9 Summary of Results Our results span two levels of comparisons – first between pre-ESL and post-ESL outcomes, which is the direct impact of ESL; the second is between the two stores through the lens of retail strategy (EDLP and HI-LO). Our estimations comprise prices, quantity sold, gross revenues, price sensitivity, price adjustments and price discovery. We find that the impact of ESL on average price levels is not to decrease prices. Rather, we 9 The detailed result of the t-test of means is given in the Appendix, in Table A7. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 22 find an increase of 13% for store S (EDLP) and no significant change for store M (HI-LO). On the other hand, ESL results in an increase of quantity sold and gross revenue for both stores – for store S (EDLP) by 17% and 31%, and for store M (HI-LO) by 8% and 6%, respectively. In absolute numbers, these are very significant levels of impact on sales volume and revenues – without lowering prices. So, this must be due to something more than just cost efficiencies.} For price sensitivity, we find the impact of ESL is quite different for the two stores. While ESL makes demand more price sensitive for store S (EDLP) it makes demand less price sensitive for store M (HI-LO). Similarly, there are differences between pre- and post-ESL price adjustments between the two stores. For store S (EDLP), ESL appears to dampen large price changes – the magnitude of average price reductions decrease from 47.2% to 28.3%, while average price increases reduce from 45.1% to 11.2%. For store M (HI-LO), on the other hand, ESL does not appear to affect average price reductions with no change between the pre- and post-ESL price reduction magnitudes. However, there is a small amplification of price increases from 13.1% to 15.2%. The findings related to price level, sensitivity and price changes are significant. Recall that one of the applications of ESL for store S (EDLP) was to better manage wastage of perishables. Traditionally end of the day deep discounts (“fire sale”) were used to clear the inventory. It appears that the ESL allows the retailer to use smaller price reductions to achieve such inventory clearance, as reflected in the higher average price levels and price sensitivity post-ESL. The smaller price reductions should directly contribute to the retailer’s bottom line. In contrast, recall that one of the applications of ESL for store M (HI-LO) was to offer greater value to its customers through the provision of relevant information. It appears that the store is able to do that – its customers are less price sensitive in the post-ESL period, which would be expected if price is no more the key criterion for purchase decisions. If customers were to give more relative weight to the information and the other non-price related sources of value offered by ESL in making purchase decisions, it lessens the price pressure faced by the retailer. Consistent with this, it also appears that the retailer is able to sustain higher price increases, albeit by smaller amounts than the EDLP store, and albeit the aggregate price increase is not statistically significant. With respect to price discovery, we cannot compare the two stores since we are only able to estimate it for store M (HI-LO). We estimate a significantly lesser lag in the extent to which its Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 23 prices depend on past prices – 2.13 weeks for the post-ESL prices compared to 3.21 weeks for its pre-ESL prices. This observation is consistent with the idea that ESL allows retailers greater efficiencies of discovery, experimentation and learning, thereby responding to more cognate relevant information in their price optimization efforts. Indeed, store M (HI-LO) seems to use information that is more current, in setting its prices, in the post-ESL period. In essence, ESL seems to allow the EDLP store achieve better pricing consistency by dampening its price changes. On the other hand, ESL seems to allow the HI-LO store to emphasize the non-price value and shift the consumer from narrowly focussing on price. Both these outcomes seem to match the strategic imperatives of the respective stores. 6. DISCUSSION Substantively, our main effort here is to understand how an emerging retail technology, ESL, affects retail outcomes. Our data comes from a field implementation of the ESL technology, covering almost two years around the installation date. The “field” aspect of the design brings with it some benefits of external validity. Further, given our experimental design with distinct treatment and control groups, as well as the longitudinal Difference-in-Difference (DID) model used in the analyses, we are able to draw “causal” inferences with greater certainty. Much of the causal inferences we are able to draw point to one primary conclusion – ESL can be used to engage in better pricing practices, which in turn drives better retail outcomes. In concluding this, we implicitly characterize “better pricing” as being intimately tied to retail strategy, such that, it is the better fit between strategy and implementation of pricing that makes the pricing better, and which drives retail outcomes like superior sales and revenue. Thus, “better outcomes” are not pre-ordained as immutable characteristics of ESL systems. Rather, the key issue seems to be whether characteristics of ESL allow retailers to better implement their pricing tactics to support their idiosyncratic retail strategy. Thus, ESL has shades of a strategic capability for retailers. At the same time, ESL’s promise to reduce menu costs and its attendant implication for price rigidity has a direct bearing on how we interpret the technology and its impact from a policy perspective. We frame our subsequent discussions through these twin lenses – strategy and policy. ESL as a Dynamic Capability: Best Practi ces Strategy Enabler ESL systems are big-ticket expenses by the retailer – of the order of a couple of hundred Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 24 thousand dollars for one supermarket store – representing a significant investment for a chain- wide adoption across multiple stores. Not surprisingly, retail managers are concerned with the ROI from such strategic investments. On this, our results appear to bring good news for retail managers, that ESL can significantly enhance retail sales volumes and revenue, two key traditional measures of retail performance. There seem to be at least four related ways these advantages of ESL accrue: reduction in menu costs, greater efficiency in waste management, providing greater value to consumers and better price discovery. However, the key takeaway from our results is that ESL acts as an enabling technology for the retailers – facilitating the implementation of their idiosyncratic store positioning strategies to create and claim value. For the EDLP store, the key impact of ESL is felt in its ability to dampen the end of the day “fire sale” nature of price cuts necessitated by unsold inventory of perishable produce. With an ability to readily adjust prices and find the “sweet spot”, the EDLP store is able to achieve a lower level of aggregate price cuts (and hence a smaller range to which price goes back up after the promotion) to clear the same level of inventory as before the implementation of ESL. This reflects in the higher aggregate price sensitivity of demand in the post-ESL period. For the HI-LO store, the key impact of ESL appears to be in its ability to offer greater value to its customers in the form of better product related information. In this, the store effectively reduces the centrality of price in the consumer decisions, which reflects in the lower aggregate price sensitivity of demand achieved in the post-ESL period. For the store, finding this sweet spot between value and price point is an onerous task. To this end, we find evidence that the store engages in more price optimization and discovery in the post-ESL period. The idea that ESL enables retailers effectively integrate their pricing, inventory and marketing resources to better implement their positioning strategies indicate ESL enhances the competitive advantages for the retailer, and as such, it has the dimensions of a strategic capability. In particular, given that ESL allows the retailer to make quick adjustments in response to changes in its business environment, be it competition, demand or supply conditions, it is a dynamic capability as envisaged by Eisenhardt and Martin (2000). Eisenhardt and Martin’s (2000) view of dynamic capability sought to demarcate boundaries between “best practices” and dynamic capabilities that impart competitive advantage, sustainable or not. While ESL could be seen as a “best practice” across the industry and any retailer could invest in ESL, there would be idiosyncratic differences in the manner different retailers would Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 25 use the technology to integrate its existing resources to implement their specific strategies. In our data, for example, the EDLP store combined pricing and inventory to achieve waste management efficiencies. At the core of this outcome was that ESL enabled the EDLP store converge on a narrower band of price changes that would effectively limit their end-of-the day inventory of unsold perishable produce. The HI-LO store, on the other hand, combined product information and pricing to achieve better value extraction. At the core of this outcome was that ESL enabled the HI-LO store to communicate more effectively with their customers while engaging in more effective price discovery. The lesson from the above in our retail context is that the right strategy per se does not necessarily yield competitive advantage. Effective implementation of that strategy is crucial. In circumstances where the implementation itself may be too costly, the retailer will not derive any advantage from its strategy. However, technologies like ESL may allow retailers to achieve both operational efficiencies as well as enhance value extracted from its customer transactions, thereby yielding a strategic dividend on their investments. Several past papers allude to the potential of ESL enabling strategic capabilities of the retailer (cf. Dutta, et al. 2003; Levy et al. 1997; Zbaracki et al. 2004; Ray et al. 2006; Bergen et al. 2008). However, to the best of our knowledge, this is the first study to offer direct evidence of its strategic impact. ESL through a Policy Lens: Menu Cost Saver While we illustrate the strategic value of ESL in the earlier discussions, from a policy lens, the impact of ESL is nuanced. An explicit function of ESLs, as argued in earlier literature, has been that it reduces menu costs, which are the direct or physical component of the retailer’s total price adjustment costs (Levy et al. 1997). The associated menu cost theories in the monetary policy literature (Barro 1972, Sheshinski and Weiss 1977, Mankiw 1985, Ball and Mankiw 1994) suggest that such lower menu costs would make prices less rigid. In fact, several jurisdictions specifically incorporate menu cost savings as considerations in enacting their pricing policies (see Bergen et al. 2008 with respect to Item Pricing Law). Our results illustrate that this policy impact also depends on retailer strategy. Whereas, ESL enables the EDLP store to achieve greater pricing consistency by allowing them to dampen the magnitude of price changes, it works differently for the HI-LO store. For Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 26 the latter, ESL appears to enable the retailer extract greater value by effectively lowering the price sensitivity of their customers, without significantly affecting their pricing patterns. Thus, the policy impact of the ESL technology appears to be ordered by the prevalent retail strategy. This builds on an emerging literature in marketing, which explores how the extent of variation in micro-level price rigidity could be strategic in nature (Ray et al. 2006; 2012). Managerial Implications The immediate managerial implications of our results pertain to the cost-benefit calculus facing the retailer tasked with the decision to implement ESL. Our results show that traditional efficiency arguments related to operational cost savings (e.g. menu costs) are conservative. A key benefit associated with ESL in our data is that of yielding strategic dividend. In other words, the large investments needed to implement ESL must be measured against its potential to generate and claim transactional value, as well. At the same time, it is important to note that while different retailers interested in gaining market advantage may adopt the ESL technology as industry “best practices,” the key to generating competitive advantage is to deploy ESL in combination with the retailer’s other strategic resources. Thus, the retailer must identify the short-term and long-term benefits as it engages with the ESL technology. In the short run, the retailer can save in menu costs. However, these “plug and play” benefits of ESL are not likely to bear competitive advantage for long. To achieve the long run benefits of better pricing and effective communications, the retailer must actively engage in a phase of learning and experimentation. It is through these options and opportunities that the retailer may realize the idiosyncratic benefits of ESL in the form of sustainable competitive advantages. 7. CONCLUSIONS AND LIMITATIONS To conclude, we use longitudinal data from a field experiment to show that ESL leads to better pricing, thereby enhancing retail sales and revenue. Underlying this result is its role as an enabling technology that helps the retailer more effectively implement its store positioning strategy. The ben efits of ESL span both efficiency and value, and are derived from its impact on price sensitivity, price adjustment patterns, and price discovery modes of the retailer. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first study to explore and quantify how a price display technology like ESL can affect retail pricing and outcomes, and how these effects are contingent on retail Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 27 strategy. In these, our study builds on the emerging literature in micro-level price rigidity as a strategic variable and identifies boundaries of its implications for macro level monetary policy. A limitation in our study is the small sample of stores and limited product categories, a common theme across most field experiments of this nature. Regardless, we hope our results and efforts will encourage future researchers to explore further the role of pricing technology in setting prices. We also hope that future work will be able to overcome some of the limitations of this study and contribute towards greater generalizability of the findings we report. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 28 REFRENCES Adams, Brian, and Kevin Williams (2019), “Zone Pricing in Retail Oligopoly,” American Economic Journal: Micro 11(1), 124–156. Aghion, P., P. Bolton, C. Harris, and B. Jullien (1991), “Optimal Learning by Experimentation,” Review of Economic Studies 58, 621–654. Alvarez, Fernando, and Francesco Lippi (2014), “Price Setting with Menu Cost for Multiproduct Firms,” Econometrica 82(1), 89–135. Argente, David, and Chen Yeh (2016), “A Menu Cost Model with Price Experimentation,” manuscript, the University of Chicago. Bachmann, Rüdiger, and Giuseppe Moscarini (2011), “Business Cycles and Endogenous Uncertainty,” Economic Dynamics Meeting Papers, No. 36. Ball, Laurence, and N. Gregory Mankiw (1994), “A Sticky-Price Manifesto,” Carnegie- Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 127–152. Balvers, R. and T. Cosimano (1993), “Periodic Learning about a Hidden State Variable,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 17, 805–827. Barro, Robert J. (1972), “A Theory of Monopolistic Price Adjustment,” Review of Economic Studies 39(1), 17–26. Baudry, L., H. Le Bihan, P. Sevestre, and S. Tarrieu (2007), “What Do Thirteen Million Price Records Have to Say about Consumer Price Rigidity?” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 69(2), 139–183. Bergen, M., D. Levy, S. Ray, P. Rubin, and B. Zeliger (2008), “When Little Things Mean a Lot: on the Inefficiency of Item Pricing Laws,” Journal of Law and Economics 24, 491–539. Bolton, Ruth, and Venkatesh Shankar (2018), “Emerging Retailer Pricing Trends and Practices,” in the Handbook of Research on Retailing, Edited by Katrijn Gielens and Els Gijsbrechts (New York, NY: Edward Elgar Publishing), pp. 104–131. Campbell, Jeffrey, and Benjamin Eden (2014), “Rigid Prices: Evidence from US Scanner Data,” International Economic Review 55(2), 423–442. Cavallo, Alberto (2018), “Scraped Data and Sticky Prices,” Review of Economics Statistics 100(1), 105–119. DellaVigna, Stefano, and Matthew Gentzkow (2019), “Uniform Pricing in US Retail Chains,” Quarterly Journal of Economics (forthcoming). Dhyne, Emmanuel and Jerzy Konieczny (2007) “Temporal Distribution of Price Changes: Staggering in the Large and Synchronization in the Small,” Working Paper Series 01-07, Rimini Centre for Economic Analysis. Dutta, S., M. Bergen, D. Levy, and R. Venable (1999), “Menu Costs, Posted Prices, and Multiproduct Retailers,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 31, 683–703. Dutta, S., M. Zbaracki, and M. Bergen (2003), “Pricing Process as a Capability: a Resource- Based Perspective,” Strategic Management Journal 24(7), 615–630. Eisenhardt, Kathleen M., Martin, Jeffrey A. (2000), “Dynamic Capabilities: What Are They?” Strategic Management Journal 21, 1105–1121. Gedenk, K., Neslin, S. A., & Ailawadi, K. L. (2010). “Sales Promotion.” In M. Krafft, and M. K Mantrala (Eds.), Retailing in the 21st Century. (Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer Berlin Heidelberg), pp. 345–360. Grewal, D., Ailawadi, K. L., Gauri, D., Hall, K., Kopalle, P., and Robertson, J. R. (2011), “Innovations in Retail Pricing and Promotions,” Journal of Retailing 87(S1), 43–52. Garaus, Marion, Elisabeth Wolfsteiner, and Udo Wagner (2016), “Shoppers’ Acceptance and Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 29 Perceptions of Electronic Shelf Labels,” Journal of Business Research 69, 3687–3692. Guadalupi, Carla (2014), “Strategic Experimentation and Price Signaling: Low Prices Signal High Quality,” manuscript. Hallberg, Niklas (2017), “The Micro-Foundations of Pricing Strategy in Industrial Markets: A Case Study in the European Packaging Industry,” Journal of Business Research 76, 179–88. Karadi, Peter and Adam Reiff (2012), “Large Shocks in Menu Cost Models,” Working Paper No. 1453, European Central Bank, Frankfurt. Keil, Sev, David Reibstein, and Dick Wittink (2001), “The Impact of Business Objectives and the Time Horizon of Performance Evaluation on Pricing Behavior,” International Journal of Research in Marketing 18(1-2), 67–81. Lach, Saul and Daniel Tsiddon (1996), “Staggering and Synchronization in Price-Setting: Evidence from Multiproduct Firms,” American Economic Review 86(5), 1175–1196. Lach, Saul and Daniel Tsiddon (2007), “Small Price Changes and Menu Costs,” Managerial and Decision Economics 28(7), 649–656. Levy, D., Bergen, M., Dutta, S., and Venable, R. (1997), “The Magnitude of Menu Costs: Direct Evidence from Large US Supermarket Chains,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, 791– 825. Levy, D., Dutta, S., Bergen, M., and Venable, R. (1998), “Price Adjustment at Multiproduct Retailers,” Managerial and Decision Economics 19, 81–120. Levy, D., G. Müller, H. Chen, M. Bergen, and S. Dutta (2010), “Holiday Price Rigidity and Cost of Price Adjustment,” Economica 77, 172–198. Mankiw, N. Gregory (1985), “Small Menu Costs and Large Business Cycles: a Macroeconomic Model of Monopoly,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 100, 529–39. Midrigan, V. (2011), “Menu Costs, Multi-Product Firms, and Aggregate Fluctuations,” Econometrica 79, 1139–1180. Ray, S., H. Chen., M. Bergen, and D. Levy (2006), “Asymmetric Wholesale Pricing: Theory and Evidence,” Marketing Science 25, 131–54. Ray, Sourav, Charles Wood, and Paul Messinger (2012), “Multicomponent Systems Pricing: Rational Inattention and Downward Rigidities,” Journal of Marketing 76, 1–17. Research and Markets (2017a), “Global Electronic Shelf Label Market 2018-2022.” ID: 4447181. Retrieved July 21, 2019 from http://tiny.cc/mu209y. Research and Markets (2017b), “Electronic Shelf Labels Market in the US 2017-2021.” ID: 4225889. Retrieved July 21, 2019 from http://tiny.cc/8n209y. Rotemberg, Julio J. (1982), “Sticky Prices in the United States,” Journal of Political Economy 90, 1187–211. Rotemberg, Julio J. (1987), “The New Keynesian Microfoundations,” NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 69–104. Rustichini, Aldo, and Asher Wolinksy (1995), “Learning about Variable Demand in the Long Run,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 19, 1283–1292. Sheshinski, Eytan, and Yoram Weiss (1977), “Inflation and Costs of Price Adjustments,” Review of Economic Studies 44, 287–303. Slade, Margaret (1998), “Optimal Pricing with Costly Adjustment: Evidence from Retail- Grocery Prices,” Review of Economic Studies 65, 87–107. Soutjis, Bastien, Franck Cochoy, and Johan Hagberg (2017), “An Ethnography of Electronic Shelf Labels: The Resisted Digitalization of Prices in Contemporary Supermarkets,” Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services 39, 296–304. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 30 Zbaracki, M., M. Bergen, and D. Levy (2007), ‘‘The Anatomy of a Price Cut: Discovering Organizat ion Sources of the Cost of Price Adjustment,’’ manuscript, Bar-Ilan University and Emory University. Zbaracki, M., M. Ritson, D. Levy, S. Dutta, and M. Bergen (2004), ‘‘Managerial and Customer Costs of Price Adjustment: Direct Evidence from Industrial Markets,’’ Review of Economics and Statistics 86, 514–533. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 31 Figure 1. Sample Comparison of Average Weekly Unit Prices across Stores Note: We use 91 weeks for Store S and 71 weeks for Store M for the illustration in order to approximately balance the number of weeks before and after ESL. Figure 2. Average Percentage Price Changes 2 2 .5 3 3 .5 4 a ve ra ge w ee kl y pr ic e 1 6 11 16 21 26 31 36 41 46 51 56 61 66 71 76 81 86 91 week StoreS (EDLP); Treatment EAN::8008110260095 ESL 47.2 28.3 45.1 11.2 0 10 20 30 40 50 Before After % p ric e ch an ge Average price changes in S (EDLP) -ve (%) +ve (%) 19.9 19.3 13.1 15.2 0 5 10 15 20 25 Before After % p ric e ch an ge Average price changes in M (HI-LO) -ve (%) +ve (%) Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 32 Table 1. Sample Size for Analyses Store S (EDLP) Store M (HI-LO) Department Before After Before After # of weeks 53 42 53 33 F&V (Treatment) # of products 26 26 335 273 # of data points 422 302 9,097 4,543 Fresh Meat (Control) # of products 17 11 61 87 # of data points 422 389 1,636 1,402 Table 2. Average Weekly Price, Sales and Gross Revenues Store S (EDLP) Before After Mean Std. Dev. Mean Std. Dev. F&V (Treatment) Unit price (€) 1.59 0.65 2.58 1.18 Sales (units) 12.88 8.91 9.36 19.73 Revenue ( × 100 €) 19.61 18.70 18.83 27.00 Fresh Meat (Control) Unit price (€) 1.48 0.65 3.10 1.52 Sales (units) 17.00 12.10 5.60 4.92 Revenue ( × 100 €) 24.24 20.88 14.43 9.30 Store M (HI-LO) Before After Mean Std. Dev. Mean Std. Dev. F&V (Treatment) Unit price (€) 1.73 0.83 1.69 0.75 Sales (units) 22.96 38.55 23.13 31.67 Revenue ( × 100 €) 36.90 66.95 35.30 45.25 Fresh Meat (Control) Unit price (€) 5.43 3.48 5.42 3.47 Sales (units) 25.29 92.85 14.65 55.75 Revenue ( × 100 €) 249.67 1,071.11 144.29 748.84 Note: Average weekly price computed from the daily median price. The revenue figures are based on actual prices. Sales reports the average weekly quantity identified in the data. Table 3. Comparison of Store Level Scale of Transactions – Before and After ESL Store S (EDLP) Store M (HI-LO) 6 month before ESL 6 month after ESL 6 month before ESL 6 month after ESL # of receipt 50,072 48,880 84,641 85,921 # of receipts/month 8,345.33 8,146.67 14,106.83 14,320.17 Avg transaction (€) 24.75 25.79 15.58 16.83 Avg Rev/yr (€) 2,478,509 2,521,620 2,637,957 2,892,762 Avg transaction /wk (€) 1,925.85 1,880 3,255.42 3,304.65 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 33 Table 4. Difference-in-Difference Estimates (a) DID for Data Pooled Across the Two Stores BEFORE AFTER Outcome Variable Control Treated Diff(pre) Control Treated Diff(post) DID (δ) ln(Unit Price) 2.45 0.907 –1.543 2.488 0.924 –1.564 –0.021 Std. Error 0.071 0.258 0.251 0.078 0.26 0.251 0.011 t 34.46 –3.52 –6.14 2.94 0.86 –1.63 –1.91 P > |t| 0 0 0.000*** 0 0 0.000*** 0.056* ln(Sales Vol) 1.471 1.003 –0.468 1.533 1.163 –0.37 0.098 Std. Error 0.203 0.739 0.719 0.223 0.745 0.719 0.032 t 7.24 0.84 –0.65 1.75 1.2 –0.33 3.09 P > |t| 0 0.175 0.515 0 0.118 0.607 0.002*** ln(Revenue) 4.024 1.917 –2.106 4.131 2.098 –2.033 0.073 Std. Error 0.205 0.746 0.725 0.225 0.752 0.726 0.032 t 19.61 1.2 –2.9 4.5 2.12 –2.01 2.27 P > |t| 0 0.01 0.004*** 0 0.005 0.005*** 0.023** (b) DID for Store S (EDLP) BEFORE AFTER Outcome Variable Control Treated Diff(pre) Control Treated Diff(post) DID (δ) ln(Unit Price) –0.669 0.855 1.524 –0.457 1.198 1.655 0.131 Std. Error 0.075 0.348 0.343 0.095 0.353 0.344 0.038 t –8.89 3.71 4.44 1.55 1.44 1.9 3.46 P > |t| 0 0.014 0.000*** 0 0.001 0.000*** 0.001*** ln(Sales Vol) 2.558 –0.16 –2.718 2.361 –0.183 –2.544 0.174 Std. Error 0.115 0.534 0.526 0.146 0.542 0.527 0.058 t 22.17 –2.54 –5.17 1.21 –0.04 –2.39 3 P > |t| 0 0.764 0.000*** 0 0.735 0.000*** 0.003*** ln(Revenue) 1.924 0.694 –1.231 1.935 1.012 –0.923 0.308 Std. Error 0.131 0.605 0.596 0.166 0.614 0.598 0.066 t 14.71 –0.11 –2.06 1.99 1.21 –0.72 4.69 P > |t| 0 0.252 0.039** 0 0.1 0.123 0.000*** Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 34 (c) DID for Store M (HI-LO) BEFORE AFTER Outcome Variable Control Treated Diff(pre) Control Treated Diff(post) DID (δ) ln(Unit Price) 2.466 3.062 0.596 2.464 3.042 0.578 –0.018 Std. Error 0.035 0.258 0.259 0.035 0.258 0.259 0.012 t 70.91 4.78 2.31 2.42 2.99 0.53 –1.51 P > |t| 0 0 0.021** 0 0 0.026** 0.132 ln(Sales Vol) 1.399 0.098 –1.301 1.058 –0.161 –1.22 0.082 Std. Error 0.098 0.726 0.728 0.1 0.726 0.728 0.034 t 14.3 –0.39 –1.79 –2.02 –0.13 –1.19 2.39 P > |t| 0 0.893 0.074* 0 0.824 0.094* 0.017** ln(Revenue) 3.948 3.14 –0.808 3.628 2.879 –0.75 0.058 Std. Error 0.099 0.734 0.736 0.101 0.734 0.737 0.035 t 39.88 2.85 –1.1 0.78 2.9 –0.73 1.69 P > |t| 0 0 0.272 0 0 0.309 0.091* ***p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 35 Table 5. ADL(1,1,) 2SLS Instrumental Variable Regression – Treatment Group (F&V) Dep Var: ( )ln itq S (EDLP) M (Hi-LO) coeff (t) coeff (t) ( ), 1ln i tq − : 1β 0.084* 0.471*** (0.048) (0.011) ( )ln itp : 2β -0.402 -9.752*** (0.648) (0.298) ( ), 1ln i tp − : 3β 0.022 4.357*** (0.619) (0.311) ( )ln itp ×ESL: 1γ -6.896*** 1.512*** (1.489) (0.391) ( ), 1ln i tp − ×ESL: 2γ 5.519*** -0.198 (1.633) (0.380) ESL: 3 1.501 -0.525*** (1.111) (0.108) α 1.791*** 3.655*** (0.345) (0.129) n 508 7,943 F Statistics 5.550 730.050 R2 0.150 0.471*** Price Elasticity 2 + 1 -7.297*** -8.240*** (-5.43) (-30.1) ***p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1 Table 6. First Difference 2SLS Instrumental Variable Regression – Treatment Group (F&V) Dep Var: ( )ln itq∆ S (EDLP) M (Hi-LO) coeff (t) coeff (t) ( )ln itp∆ : 1β 0.299 –8.892*** (1.156) (–35.709) ( )ln itp∆ ×ESL: 1γ –2.061*** 1.830*** (–3.104) (5.432) ESL: 2β –0.065 –0.021 (–0.648) (–1.246) α –0.021 –0.059*** (–0.338) (–5.193) R2 0.021 0.228 ***p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 36 Table 7. Average Percentage Price Changes Before and After ESL – by Store S (EDLP) M (Hi-LO) Before After Before After Absolute price change % N 476 426 11,644 12,872 mean 45.3 11.7 14.9 16.3 SD 312.9 198.9 28.8 224.1 Negative price change % N 61 14 3166 3471 mean –47.2 –28.3 –19.9 –19.3 SD 27.9 16.2 16 16 Positive price change % N 415 412 8,478 9,401 mean 45.1 11.2 13.1 15.2 SD 335 202.2 32.1 262 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 37 APPENDIX Table A1. Store Size Comparisons Store Characteristics Store S (EDLP) Store M (HI-LO) Gross Profit % (2009) 35.0% 37.5% Like for like sales growth (2009) 3.00% 3.00% Expense as % of sales (2009) 23.8% 4.2% Wage rate per labour hour £ (2009) 9.00 12.00 Annual sales € (2008) 2.48m 2.64m Average purchase per receipt € (2008) 24.75 15.58 Average no. of transactions per week (2008) 1925 3255 Table A2. Average Weekly % Changes (Absolute Value) – Price ∆p, Sales ∆q, and Revenue ∆Rev Store S (EDLP) Store M (HI-LO) No. Department n |∆p| |∆q| |∆Rev| n |∆p| |∆q| |∆Rev| 3 Fresh Meat 403 13.5 27.7 33.1 786 36.9 64.9 83.4 4 Fruit & Veg 282 42.4 98.0 153.0 3,797 12.7 67.0 64.6 6 Dairy products 9,499 47.4 83.6 127.6 16,548 2.9 84.5 78.7 7 Bread 79 36.9 54.8 87.6 700 8.7 29.3 30.7 8 Deep-frozen food 5,780 3.2 87.3 78.3 10 General store 812 0.6 67.1 63.9 Note: Average changes computed for the period before ESL – 49 weeks for Store S (EDLP), 35 weeks for Store M (HI-LO). The number of EAN codes used for the estimation is n. Table A3. Regression of Price, Sales Volume and Revenue for Time Trend – Fresh Meat Department Price Sales Vol Revenue S (EDLP) M (HI-LO) S (EDLP) M (HI-LO) S (EDLP) M (HI-LO) Indep var. Coeff (t) Coeff (t) Coeff (t) Coeff (t) Coeff (t) Coeff (t) week –0.012 0.016 –0.015 –0.030 –0.029 –0.016 (–1.089) (0.491) (–0.806) (–0.371) (–1.494) (–0.191) week2 0.000 –0.000 –0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 (1.033) (–0.350) (–0.091) (0.386) (0.506) (0.262) ESL×week 0.049*** –0.024 –0.013 0.079 0.047 0.059 (2.874) (–0.655) (–0.469) (0.892) (1.634) (0.641) ESL×week2 –0.001** 0.000 0.000 –0.000 –0.000 –0.000 (–2.323) (0.486) (0.823) (–0.904) (–0.863) (–0.719) ESL –0.336 0.053 –1.088** –2.148 –1.709*** –2.258 (–1.105) (0.038) (–2.206) (–0.613) (–3.325) (–0.616) α 0.525*** 0.745 10.087*** 2.652 3.786*** 3.497 (2.775) (0.579) (32.872) (0.836) (11.840) (1.055) Number of obs 812 5234 812 5234 812 5234 F statistics 90.28 750.32 91.18 84.34 21.64 4.47 Adj R-squared 0.36 0.42 0.36 0.07 0.11 0.00 ***p < 0.01; **p < 0.05; *p < 0.1 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 38 Table A4. Robustness of DID Estimates – Placebo Test Before ESL (Sample 1) After ESL (Sample 2) S (EDLP) Wk 23 Wk 33 Wk 43 Wk 73 Wk 83 Unit price sig. not sig. not sig. not sig. not sig. Volume not sig. not sig. not sig. not sig. not sig. Gross revenue sig. not sig. not sig. not sig. not sig. M (HI-LO) Wk 30 Wk 40 Wk 50 Wk 80 Wk 90 Unit price sig. sig. not sig. not sig. sig. Volume not sig. not sig. not sig. not sig. not sig. Gross revenue not sig. not sig. not sig. not sig. not sig. Table A5. Instrumental Variables Instruments Category M (HI-LO) S (EDLP) p1jt Canned food √√ √√ p2jt Canned non-food √√ p5jt Delicatessen √√ √√ p6jt Dairy products √√ √√ p7jt Bread √√ pointjit Loyalty points √√ √√ Table A6. Instrumental Variables for ADL(1,0) – Endogenous ( )ln itp∆ Instruments Category M (HI-LO) S (EDLP) ∆ p1jt Canned food √√ √√ ∆ p2jt Canned non-food √√ ∆ p5jt Delicatessen √√ √√ ∆ p6jt Dairy products √√ √√ ∆ p7jt Bread √√ ∆ pointjit Loyalty points √√ √√ Table A7. Comparison of Average Lag – t-Test for Means BEFORE Max. of lags (N1) AFTER Max. of lags (N2) Mean 3.2105 2.1316 Variance 4.4950 3.2525 Observations 38 38 Pearson Correlation 0.5934 Hypothesized Mean Difference 0 df 37 t-Stat 3.7124 P(T ≤ t) one-tail 0.0003 t-Critical one-tail 1.6871 P(T ≤ t) two-tail 0.0007 t-Critical two-tail 2.0262 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547 39 Figure A1. Impact of Natural Log Transformation (a) Store S (EDLP) – Distribution of Sales Volume (b) Store M (HI-LO) – Distribution of Sales Volume Figure A2. Summary DID estimates – Pooled and by Store (a) DID on Pooled data (b) DID by Store 0 .0 2 .0 4 .0 6 .0 8 D en si ty 0 100 200 300 sales volume 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 D en si ty 0 2 4 6 logarithm of sales volume 0 .0 1 .0 2 .0 3 .0 4 D en si ty 0 100 200 300 400 sales volume 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 D en si ty 0 2 4 6 logarithm of sales volume δ -2% 10% 7% -5% 0% 5% 10% 15% Price Volume Revenue δ 13% -2% 17% 8% 31% 6% -10% 0% 10% 20% 30% 40% S (EDLP) M (HI-LO) Price Volume Revenue not sig. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3438547

admin

Author admin

More posts by admin